Introduction To The History Of Trucking And Transportation
The history of trucking and transportation has followed an interesting trajectory. A good portion of the transportation that is still used today was invented in the twentieth century, a time period in which most of the earlier forms of transportation rapidly became obsolete. The history of trucking is just another part of the picture. The history of trucking changed very rapidly once the twentieth century began, although the history of trucking technically dates back to the late nineteenth century.
Trucking Before 1900
Railroads were basically the trucks of their day. Freight was moved from place to place using railroads in the nineteenth century. Railroads were considered wonderfully impressive inventions at the time, and many people treated railroads as symbols of the fact that they were living in an era of tremendous technological and social progress. A good portion of the people who became wealthy in the nineteenth century did so by investing in railroads.
Railroads almost serve as a symbol of the fact that the nineteenth century was indeed an impressive time period full of rapid social and technological change, but the twentieth century was more impressive and the changes were more dramatic. The twenty-first century appears to be leaving the twentieth century in the dust as well, continuing this trend.
As impressive as railroads were, the freight could still only travel in highly predetermined paths, and the freight was often limited to the most centralized urban areas. From there, the freight was still moved using vehicles pulled by horses. Railroading was a departure from traditional modes of transportation, but it was still dependent on earlier modes of transportation and limited in terms of what it could accomplish.
The rise of trucking made all the difference in terms of the movement of freight, but trucking didn’t really begin until the twentieth century. There were trucks in the nineteenth century, but they were treated as showpieces and technological marvels as opposed to valuable tools. Their utility was primarily for advertising revenue.
It should be noted that one of the biggest boosts to the trucking industry was the widespread growth of paved roads. Roads were much less extensive in the nineteenth century, especially in rural areas. The roads that people would find there weren’t paved. Even if trucks were more advanced in terms of the technology, they weren’t going to be as useful as the trucks today just because the infrastructure of the nineteenth century was not up to the task.
However, the technological limitations of the earlier trucks were certainly nothing to sneeze at for anyone. These trucks used electric engines. It is true that electric engines are praised today for being more environmentally friendly than the internal combustion engines that they could theoretically replace. However, today, the storage batteries for the electric charges are much more efficient. People are capable of traveling longer distances on a single charge. It is also possible to design lots of different refueling stations in the modern world, which would theoretically make it easier for electric engines to be adopted on a wider scale.
Even with the earlier internal combustion engines, drivers were often limited in terms of the distance that they could cover due to the lack of refueling stations on their journeys. With electric engines, the engines would run out of the necessary power fairly early in the process. Drivers could only travel using electric engines using a very narrow driving range.
Modern trucks are also distinguished by the fact that they have tremendously large load capacities. The trucks of the nineteenth century were miniature by comparison. Even if the infrastructure were in place to allow people to travel longer distances and even if the electric engines were more efficient than they were, people still would not be able to carry much in the way of freight using the earliest nineteenth century trucks. As such, the entire process would not be especially cost-effective for anyone.
Traveling much more than short distances in these trucks also would have been unsafe and nearly torturous. Trucking today is often a difficult and dangerous job. Truckers work long hours, and they’re technically getting exposed to the pollution of the road and the sun all day long. The earliest trucks were amazingly even worse when it came to exposing the drivers to the elements. Early vehicles in general were extremely unsafe compared to the vehicles of today. A good portion of the safety features that people take for granted did not become standard until the late twentieth century. The temperature fluctuations that bother truckers today would have been torturous for the people who were driving the trucks of the nineteenth century.
However, the trucks of the nineteenth century were certainly an important part of the process. They served as a template for the trucks that would shortly arrive on the scene in a more influential manner. Technology builds on itself, and the trucking industry of the twentieth and twenty-first century had to get its start with some prototypes. The nineteenth century provided those prototypes.
Railroads also helped set the precedent for being able to move large amounts of freight over long distances. People were already used to that at this point during nineteenth century history, which made the transition to the modern trucking industry that much easier for the people of the time.
Trucking in 1910
The internal combustion engine was technically invented in 1884, but the gasoline-powered internal combustion engine didn’t really become an economic and cultural force to be reckoned with until the 1910’s. There were other technological improvements during this time period when it came to early trucks, including the switch from chain drives to gear drives. Gear drives last much longer and are easier to use.
The combination of the tractor and the semi-trailer that is so iconic today began during this time period. This design made it that much easier for people to transport freight across large distances in the first place. Trucks were not going to be profitable unless they could carry large amounts of freight from one location to the next in the modern manner. The trucks of the 1910’s were some of the first trucks that were capable of doing so.
There were around one hundred thousand trucks on the road by the year 1914 in the United States. However, the trucking industry was still nothing like it is today. Early trucks had wheels made from solid rubber and iron. The rubber that people are more familiar with today was created in World War Two. The tires of old were woefully inefficient.
People today often complain about trucks wearing down the surface of asphalt roads. However, asphalt roads can withstand a lot of weight. The roads of the early twentieth century were often covered with gravel, and some of them barely even had that level of protection. The first weight limits imposed on trucks in 1913 were actually imposed in order to defend the roads against damage. The first trucks were also not capable of traveling very quickly, largely due to the nature of the tires. As such, it was not going to be very easy to try to move cargo with them anyway.
The Trucking Industry and World War I
World War One, like World War Two after it, helped create many of the facets of modern life that are taken for granted today. Railroads were strained with overuse during the years of World War One. The situation created a demand for alternatives, and the technology was in place for a new trucking industry.
Roy Chapin was the industrialist who helped pioneer the trucking industry of today. He helped found the company that set the stage for American motors. He also helped pioneer the first long-distance shipments by truck. The development of the new inflated tires, known as pneumatic tires at the time, allowed trucks to travel more quickly and more efficiently. By 1920, a million trucks were on the road. It was a steep increase from the previous six-figure estimation.
The development of the trucking industry only became more extensive over the course of the twentieth century. The New Deal policies that expanded the roads and the development of the interstate revolutionized the trucking industry. However, even before 1920, the trucking industry was already thriving.
The beginning of trucking happened earlier than many people think, which is partly due to the fact that moving freight is so economically important. Developments related to moving freight were going to occur relatively early since there is so much economic push for them. The history of transportation has always been colored by technological, cultural, and economic factors.
The early trucking industry and the beginning of the history of trucks was largely influenced by factors as major as a world war and factors as minor as a change in tire technology. Many of the developments that have transformed society got off the ground as a result of similarly modest beginnings. However, by 1920, many of the most major developments in the trucking industry were yet to come for everyone in the world.
Trucking History 1920s
The history of trucking changed dramatically between the beginning of the 1920’s and the beginning of the 1930’s. Technological and tremendous social changes managed to drive the history of trucking in the 20’s. Trucking in the 20’s specifically was largely shaped by technological change that made trucks more efficient and the economic growth that created more drivers in general, as well as the lingering effects of World War One. It was a crucial decade for the history of trucking.
Trucking in the 20’s
People in the 1920’s were still recovering from the effects of World War One in more ways than one. A huge portion of the culture of the day developed based on a reaction to the war. The government took over the railroads until the year 1920, and railroads barely had the capacity for any domestic products when they were burdened with moving around munitions and other supplies that were important to the war effort.
Domestic Products Fueled Trucking Industry
The burgeoning trucking industry began to get more involved in transporting domestic products around the country, and this didn’t stop even when the government relinquished control of the rails in the 1920’s. The trucking industry achieved more power during the war years, and the industry held onto that power and reach. A new niche had expanded, and this was a trend that was only going to continue in conjunction with many of the other cultural changes in the 1920’s.
Driving Becomes The New Norm
This new niche attracted a lot of enthusiastic entrepreneurs. Some of the same people who would have become wealthy for constructing new railroads or getting involved with the railroad business a generation ago soon started to get in on the new trucking industry that was taking shape all around them. Given the economic improvements of the 1920’s relative to earlier points during this time period, it was the perfect moment for a lot of new entrepreneurs to enter the market and try to expand this particular niche.
Automotive Industry Takes Off
One of the most striking aspects of automotive history in general during the 1920’s is the simple fact that driving went from a niche activity to a common one. There still weren’t as many drivers on the road in the 1920’s as there are today, but it was the decade in which driving was really becoming an important part of the American lifestyle.
The 1920’s was the Model T era, where cars were still black and interchangeable, but these black and interchangeable cars still helped transform the nation. Henry Ford made it possible for middle class people to own and operate their own motor vehicles, and he also managed to indirectly create a lot of new industries and technological developments in the process.
New And Improved Roads
Since driving was becoming so common, there was an incentive to update and improve the roads in rural areas. Technically, the old-fashioned roads served their purposes just fine, but they didn’t meet the needs of automobile drivers. Updating and improving the roads opened up rural areas to both cars and trucks, expanding the range of truck drivers everywhere. A lot of the resources that trucks are going to be transporting originate in the country in the first place, so being able to open up the country to trucks made all the difference in the trucking industry.
The Diesel Engine Is Born
The development of the diesel engine was also a major development in the history of trucking. Diesel engines have excellent fuel efficiency compared to gasoline engines. While today, an improvement like that would largely be praised for its environmental benefits, at the time, the improved fuel efficiency helped expand the range of trucks. Filling stations still weren’t as common as they are today. However, the introduction of more filling stations was also an important development in the history of trucking in the 20’s. The long haul truck driving jobs that are famous and infamous today started to become more commonplace during the 1920’s, along with the short haul trucking jobs.
When many people imagine trucks of the past, they are probably mainly wondering when the trucks that they would conceptualize as modern trucks emerged. The trucks made before the 1920’s looked like motorized wagons and ran more like motorized wagons. People today would visually recognize 1920’s trucks as modern trucks. The cabs of the trucks became enclosed, which helped complete the look. The important fifth wheels of trucks were also introduced during the 1920’s, and these were essential for the sake of hooking up trailers in the first place.
Filling Stations Begin To Pop Up On Local Corners
American filling stations date back to the year 1905, where the first one was constructed in St. Louis, Missouri. The drive-in filling stations that people are more familiar with today got their start in 1913. The number of filling stations expanded considerably throughout the 1920’s as the number of American drivers increased and the gas stations could become more profitable.
Before this point in time, the people who needed to replenish their gasoline supplies would have to count on bringing enough gasoline with them, or they would have to hope there was a blacksmith shop, general store, or hardware store nearby. Neither strategy was going to work particularly well for trucks, so the increased availability of filling stations and the increased efficiency of trucks made all the difference in the history of trucking.
The Roaring 1920s Saw It All
Truck and trailer sizes also become standardized during the 1920’s. It was easier for the freight industry to function under those circumstances, and producing trucks on a broad scale became more efficient as a result. The standardized size and weight of trucks was also good for the new roads, so the development of both managed to reinforce each other during the 1920’s.
Safety was a huge issue with early vehicles in general, but trucks did become safer during the 1920’s as well thanks to power assisted steering and brakes. The power assisted steering and brakes made the trucks much easier to use, which made it possible for more people to drive trucks. Trucking in the 1920’s was largely driven by technological and economic progress, which makes complete sense in the era that is still known as the Roaring Twenties.
Trucking History 1930s
The trucking industry suffered throughout the Great Depression of the 1930’s just like every other industry, but the industry did still manage to make some progress during this time period nonetheless. Some entrepreneurs still succeeded, taking advantage of the economic stratification that occurs during times of economic depression. The governmental reforms of the decade helped truckers then, and have continued to help truckers now within the framework of the history of trucking. Trucking in the 30’s continued in spite of everything, making trucking seem like a fitting metaphor for the time period in general.
Trucking Entrepreneurs During the Great Depression
The onset of the Great Depression changed almost everything throughout the world. Most industries suffered during the Great Depression, and the burgeoning trucking industry and freight industries were no exception. In the 1920’s, many entrepreneurs flocked to the new trucking industry in order to jump on the trend and build their fortunes. They helped make the trucking industry a force to be reckoned with in the first place, taking some of the power and domination away from railroads as a result.
A lot of these entrepreneurs were out of business by the time the Great Depression hit, and some of them never recovered their lost fortunes. However, it should be noted that the economic depressions that are bad for society as a whole can end up benefiting some of the wealthiest and most successful people in any given society.
Trucking Industry Able To Grow During Great Depression And Years After
These individuals can take advantage of the reduced competition during these bad economic times, and they can also benefit from a time period in which many items have lost value and have come down in price. These sorts of trends were specifically beneficial for the people entering the trucking industry who needed capital.
Entrepreneur W.W. Estes got a trucking business off the ground in Virginia. He didn’t need much capital in order to do so, and the capital that he did manage to get his hands on was very inexpensive. Even during the worst years of the Great Depression, his business managed to grow and succeed. W.W. Estes wasn’t the only one. The trucking industry more or less managed to contract but also expand during the ’30’s.
People in the trucking industry who managed to stay in business during the Great Depression managed to benefit from the economic recovery that started to take place after the worst years of the Great Depression, so they ultimately came out ahead even if they suffered from setbacks during the early 1930’s. Even some of the wealthiest people of the 1930’s lost everything during the Great Depression, but the wealthy people who didn’t sometimes became even richer.
New Deal Policies and the Great Depression
The Great Depression also changed the history of trucking forever, partly as a result of New Deal policies.The construction of roads expanded further as a result of the Public Works Administration, which was started as part of the New Deal in order to create more jobs throughout the United States. Thousands of miles of road were constructed through the Public Works Administration.
It is true that the creation of the interstate highway system did not really get off the ground until the 1940’s, but the development of the new roads during the Great Depression helped set the stage for these developments too, while also making a huge difference in the history of trucking in general.
American Trucking Association Formed
The lives for truck drivers improved after the early 1930’s. The American Trucking Association formed, which helped protect the interests of truckers. In 1934, a code of fair competition was created in the trucking industry, making it a more equitable industry in general. Many of the corrupt corporate practices that helped initiate the Great Depression in the first place also influenced the trucking industry, and regulations like this were partly created in order to stop that situation from arising again.
Railroad/Trucking Rivalry
The rivalry between the railroad industry and the trucking industry really started to become more heated during the 1930’s as well. Early in the decade of the 1930’s and before that point, the Interstate Commerce Commission only regulated the railroad industry. They did not regulate trucking companies. This was largely the result of cultural inertia. Railroads had been around much longer than trucking companies, some of which were actually formed in the 1930’s itself.
1930s Economic Downturn
The early 30s were hard for most Americans. The government during the 1930’s was desperate to try to fix the economic problems of the day, and they were receptive to the complaints and concerns of many different industries. The rail industry of the day was losing business to the trucking industry, largely because the trucking industry’s lack of regulation gave them something of an unfair advantage.
This lack of regulation was actually one of the reasons why some trucking entrepreneurs during this time period were able to succeed in such a bad economy. If these same people had participated in the rail industry, they would have had worse luck. The fact that trucks could now complete long haul journeys worsened a problem that had been developing for years.
Motor Carrier Act Of 1935
The government responded to the concerns voiced by the rail industry, and Congress passed the Motor Carrier Act in 1935. As a result, the trucking industry was to be regulated by the Interstate Commerce Commission. While it is true that this was partly a measure that was enacted in order to help the railroad industry, it did have benefits for the trucking industry and its employees. The Interstate Commerce Commission helped push for regulations concerning the working hours of truck drivers, which were often far too long and strenuous during the 1930’s. By 1938, hours of service regulations improved the lives of truck drivers all over the country.
Given the cultural changes that took place in response to World War Two in the 1940’s, the benefits that truck drivers received during this time period were that much more important. The lives of truck drivers would have been very different if they had been forced to work in a manner that was more consistent with earlier policies, while also trying to meet the demands of the war effort.
The trucking industry was still fairly new during the 1920’s and the 1930’s. During the 1930’s, many of the problems in the trucking industry were ironed out, creating a more stable and more equitable system. Truckers today are still benefiting from many of the reforms that took place during this time period, even if the Interstate Commerce Commission no longer exists today.
Trucking Industry During The 1950s-1960s
The construction of the interstate highway system continued during the 1960’s, so in some ways, the developments in the trucking industry that occurred during the 1950’s were continued during the 1960’s. However, trucking itself was starting to become a popular topic of discussion during the 1960’s. Trucking and the lives of truckers themselves weren’t as well known to the general public before that point in history, and this change helped shape trucking in the 60’s. However, the development of the interstate highway made trucks and truckers ubiquitous enough that neither could be ignored by the general public. Regulations regarding trucks were also refined during the 1960’s, which only helped raise awareness about trucks and truckers.
Interstate Highway Development and Pop Culture
People were moving to the suburbs in droves during the 1950’s, and commuting to the city through the new interstate highways was becoming very commonplace. Trucks were hauling items throughout the country at the same time. Drivers became used to driving right alongside the large and intimidating long-haul trucks. This was during a time period where there were few safety features for cars or trucks. Highways during the 1960’s were significantly narrower than modern highways. The speed limits were also 55 mph. The highways of the day had a way of creating camaraderie among drivers. Drivers saw truck drivers transporting everything from gasoline to logs in a society that was increasingly dependent on successful long-haul trucking.
Suburban drivers all throughout the country began discussing trucks more often, which raise both awareness and curiosity about them. The American Wild West was a popular subject during the 1950’s and the 1960’s, and the people of the day had a tendency to project those narratives onto lots of unrelated subjects, including truckers. Truckers started to be conceptualized in terms of modern cowboys riding powerful modern vehicles and surviving based on their own wits and determination. This narrative was still developing in the 1960’s, but in many respects, it has not died out even today.
Popular Trucking Songs
Films and songs about truckers and truck driving started achieving popularity during the 1960’s. There is still a stereotype today that many country songs are about trucking. Some of the first country songs about trucking were written during the 1960’s, which is also when a lot of modern music genres were being crystallized. Some of these same songs are even around today.
Driving And Music Becomes Part Of The American Culture
The first FM radio to be installed in a car was introduced in 1952. In 1963, all-transistor radios were added to cars. Listening to music in cars during long commutes was starting to become part of American culture during this time period. Unsurprisingly, a lot of people were interested in listening to songs that were about cars and driving. They liked listening to songs about the powerful trucks driving on the road next to them as well.
Field tests during the 1950’s and 1960’s demonstrated that a lot of the trucks of the day were contributing to the degradation of the new roads just due to their sheer size. In 1964, theAmerican Association of State Highway and Transportation Officials told Congress that one solution to this problem was that there should not be a solid upper weight limit for trucks. Instead, they recommended that the weight limit should be determined on a more case-by-case basis, where the weight limits were calculated based partly on the lengths of axles. This solution managed to avert a lot of potential conflicts between both sides, although it was not put into place until later.
It is possible that the discussions about the effects that the weight of trucks had on the roads only helped to cement their roguish reputation in popular culture. Naturally, professional truckers actually needed to have commercial driver’s licenses, which require their own set of training and education. There were special hours of services for truckers, and this was for the sake of other drivers on the road as well as for the truckers themselves.
The roguish image of truckers from this time period and today is somewhat dubious when the professional and rule-abiding aspects of the job are taken into account. Truckers also come in contact with police officers more than people in other professions, since they spend their careers on the road. However, people during this time period and through to the present were content to view truckers in a more symbolic way, and it seems as if a lot of truckers tried to embrace this image.
This image almost certainly inspired more people to become truck drivers in the first place. The 1960’s was a time period in which a lot of people were searching for their identities in an era of rapid social and technological progress. The restrictive lifestyle of the 1950’s and Cold War conformity left a lot of people wanting more. Some people embraced the progressive counter-cultural movements of the day. Some people embraced images of traditional masculinity, and they adopted truck driving as a profession that embodied freedom, manliness, and independence.
Naturally, the middle class 1950’s lifestyle was never accessible to everyone, and members of the working class would often have to embrace their own very different dreams. Trucking is a job that has attracted a lot of hardworking blue collar workers looking for job security for a long time, and this effect became more pronounced during the 1960’s. By the middle of the 1960’s, 8 million Americans made their living in the trucking industry.
Technological changes in trucks in the 1950’s and 1960’s helped popularize the truck driving experience further. Air conditioning, variable rear suspension, individual front suspension, and power steering all helped make these huge trucks safer and more comfortable to drive. Diesel engines became more powerful during this time period, and engine brake systems improved tremendously with the famous Jake Brake. Even new tinted windows made a big difference, helping truck drivers cope with sun exposure. Trucking driving quickly became open to more people.
The growth of interstate highways increased the number of trucks on the road. Technological and cultural changes helped popularize trucking. The increased interest in trucks and trucking caused more people to go into the profession. It isn’t surprising that there were over 18 million trucks operating in the United States by the year 1970.
How We Got Here: A History Of Regulation
The
roots of regulation of the transportation industry go back to 1887,
when Congress created the interstate Commerce Commission to oversee the
railroad industry. The purpose of the ICC was to ensure that small
communities, or communities with limited transportation access, would
not be charged excessive rates and be held financially captive by their
transportation providers. The ICC approved and set rates that controlled
how much a product could be hauled for.
Trucking came under the
control of the ICC in 1935, partly due to lobbying from the railroads,
which were losing business to the trucking industry. By the 1930’s,
trucking was no longer just an urban and short haul transporter, but was
now competing head to head with the railroads for long haul
transportation.
Under the Motor Carrier Act of 1935, new trucking
companies had to seek a “certificate of public convenience and
necessity” from the ICC. Companies already operating prior to 1935 were
grandfathered in, and got their certificates automatically if they could
document their prior service. New trucking companies found it extremely
difficult to get operating authority.
The law required companies
to file their rates or “tariffs” with the ICC 30 days before they
became effective. Anyone was allowed to protest these rates, including
competing companies or the railroads.
The regulatory landscape
changed again in 1948 with the passage of the Reed-Bulwinkle act which
exempted both the railroads and the trucking industry from anti trust
laws. This allowed trucking companies to collectively set rates for
cargo.
Trucking was broken down into three categories of freight.
“Common carriers” were the large pre 1935 existing companies, that
could apply for a tariff to haul any freight for any customers.
“Contract carriers” could only haul for a maximum of 8 customers, which
severely limited the growth of the trucking companies to the size of
their customer. Unless the customer grew, the trucking company could not
grow. And “Exempt Freight” was things that could be hauled by anyone,
at whatever price was negiotiated, but only covered a few products such
as logs, produce, cattle, and a few other items that were either very
time sensitive or the big companies did not want to handle.
Under
this system, one of the biggest issues became that of one compny buying
the authority of another in an effort to expand their business. To
understand the concept of “authority” lets look at a hypothetical
situation. You have a trucking company in Philadelphia, and you have the
authority to haul drywall to Buffalo. You find another company that has
the right to haul drywall from Buffalo, to Pittsburgh. You buy the
second company, and now you would seem have the authority to haul
drywall between Philly and Pittsburgh. In truth, the only way you can
haul is by going through Buffalo, transferring the load to another
truck, and making up a second bill of lading. You do not have authority
to haul directly between Philly and Pittsburgh. You also would need a
separate authority for another product for the return trip, or the truck
would have to return empty.
So from 1935 until 1980, the only
way to grow a trucking business was to buy up other companies with
authority to haul the products you wanted to the location you wanted to
serve. Other companies or the railroads would fight this, claiming that
they already served this market, or that they could serve that market
but the demand was not there.
By the 1970’s, the handwriting
started to appear on the wall that the system of regulation was outdated
and ineffective. Products that were exempt from regulation were able to
move at prices as much as 20-40% less than regulated commodities. For
example, regulated prices for hauling cooked poultry were almost 50%
higher than the rates for carrying unregulated fresh dressed poultry.
One
of the most famous cases illustrating the absurdity of regulation was
the “Yak Fat” case filed by a trucker in Omaha Ne. He had authority to
haul meat, but when the customer asked him to haul drums of lard, he
submitted an application to the ICC to haul the product and the
railroads protested, claiming that they were serbing the customer and
the area already. So they next filed an applcation to haul “Tibetan Yak
Fat”, and of course, the railroads protested the application. They
claimed that they were already hauling millions of tons of yak fat, and
that allowing a trucking company in would cut into their business. They
also claimed that the truckers could not haul yak fat for the rate they
proposed and the lower rate would devastate the market.
Of
course, the ICC rubberstamped the railroads protest and ruled in their
favor. The story appeared in various newspapers and business magazines,
and the owner of the trucking company was pictured with a yak at the
Omaha zoo. The Yak Fat issue was one of the prime arguments for deregulating the trucking industry.
In
the 1970’s, the Ford and Carter administrations altered the membership
of the ICC by adding commissioners who were committed to deregulation of
the trucking industry. In 1977, the ICC began to administratively
deregulate the trucking industry. between 1975 and 1979, the number of
companies applying for entry grew by over 700%, and the number approved
climbed by over 800%. In 1980. the Motor Carrier Reform Act of 1980
basically ended the regulation of most trucking companies and
commodities, and paved the way for the basic forms of trucking as we
know it today.
The deregulation of the trucking industry led to
the loss of power from the hands of unions, the end of many of the big
unionized LTL companies that prospered under regulation, and the rise of
the large truckload carriers that we see today. Companies that fought
deregulation and free market rates died, companies that embraced
deregulation prospered.
Origins of Trucking Regulation
Like
an understudy who outshines the absent star, the trucking industry
established itself during a temporary “absence” of railroads, and the
railroads never regained the spotlight. During World War I, when the
rails were nationalized to assure speedy transport of military troops
and supplies, they were often forced to suspend shipment of other
freight. Motor carriers took up the slack. The railroads returned to
private control in 1920, but by then, trucks were an accepted form of
transportation, and their use quickly expanded.
The railroads
campaigned for state controls that would limit the competitive advantage
of the trucking industry. The railroad industry had itself been
regulated for many years–both by state commissions and by the
Interstate Commerce Commission, established in 1887 for that purpose.
Maximum-rate controls shielded merchants and formers from monopolistic
pricing. Even more important as a historical explanation for regulation,
minimum-rate controls protected the railroads from one another. But the
same regulation that restrained rate cutting within the rail industry
left railroads vulnerable to competition from outside.
The state
commissions that oversaw railroads also sought controls on trucking, as a
way both to ease the decline of railroads and to expand their own
influence. Pennsylvania was the first state to adopt trucking controls,
in 1914. Thirty-five states had followed suit by 1925. These
controls–modeled after regulation of railroads and public
utilities–restricted entry into the trucking industry and limited
maximum and minimum rates that truckers could charge.
The
first proposal for federal regulation of motor carriers took shape in
1925, in response to Supreme Court decisions that upset the informal
practice of states controlling interstate trucking on the grounds that
the practice invaded a field reserved by the Commerce Clause of the
Constitution for federal regulation. The bill–drafted by the National
Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners–called for national
controls that would be administered by boards of state commissioners,
with the ICC–which had shown little interest in trucking regulation–to
intervene only in the event of an appeal. The railroads solidly
supported the proposal. Opponents included most truckers,
representatives of labor, and shipper groups. But Congress delayed
action with respect to trucks and focused instead on regulation of
buses, since railroads were still primarily concerned with the decline
in passenger traffic and revenue
When the depression settled in
several years later, the railroads were extremely hard hit, and the
pressure for trucking regulation increased. One vocal proponent was the
Security Owners’ Association–a politically powerful group of investors
in railroad securities that included more than 1,500 national and state
banks, trust companies, mutual savings banks, and life insurance
companies. In 1932, the SOA established the National Transportation
Commission, with former president Calvin Coolidge as its chairman, and
the following year the commission recommended regulation of trucking.
The
railroads’ plight also attracted the support of many politicians, most
notably Franklin Roosevelt. In a widely publicized campaign speech in
1932, presidential candidate Roosevelt called for elimination of the
“unfair competitive advantages” of the trucking industry. Once elected,
Roosevelt announced “plans for the regulation of all forms of
transportation.”
The depression also served to eliminate the trucking industry’s resistance to regulation, as Ellis Hawley describes:
With
the coming of the depression, the drastic drop in demand, and the
resulting struggle for available markets, the attitude of some of the
larger trucking firms began to change. Their position, they felt, was
seriously threatened by the appearance of cut-rate, “fly-by-night”
operators, who, with the aid of truck dealers and manufacturers, managed
to get a truck on credit, to eke out a living on cut rates until they
lost it, and in the process to force down wages and disrupt the whole
rate structure. Under the circumstances, there was growing support in
trucking, bus, and teamster circles for some type of regulation, some
system that would establish minimum rates and wages and eliminate
irresponsible operators.
Thus, in 1933, many trucking firms
welcomed the establishment of a price and wage code under the National
Industrial Recovery Act. Most truckers continued to prefer the code to
legislation that would give regulatory control to the rail-minded
ICC–the alternative favored by railroads, state rail commissions, and
Roosevelt’s federal coordinator of transportation. The motor carrier
industry–represented by the newly formed American Trucking Associations
(ATA)–was joined in its opposition to legislation by shippers and by
auto manufacturers concerned with maintaining the growing market for
trucks.
Fearful that Congress would not renew the National
Recovery Administration codes when they expired in 1935, the ATA
modified its stance on a regulatory bill and testified that the industry
was “willing to be controlled by the Federal Government” under a
reorganized ICC. But when the Supreme Court declared the NRA
unconstitutional in May of 1935, the ATA dropped its opposition to a
regulatory bill altogether and became an active sponsor of federal
controls.
With the major source of resistance now gone,
legislation passed Congress with relative ease. The Motor Carrier Act of
1935 gave the ICC broad regulatory powers over most interstate motor
carriers with respect to entry and rates, as well as labor practices,
safety, and the issuance of trucking securities. Exempted from
regulation were shippers who transported their own goods and carriers
hauling unprocessed agricultural commodities–a testament to the
political clout of “private carriers” and farmers. (In addition,
intrastate trucking remained subject solely to state regulation.) With
its domain only slightly narrowed by these exemptions, the ICC set out
to reduce competitive disturbances both within the trucking industry and
between trucking and rail.
The following years saw dramatic
changes in the ICC and the industries it oversaw. Once regarded
suspiciously by the trucking industry, the commission gradually adopted
an attitude toward motor carriers that was strongly protectionist. The
regulated trucking industry changed too–from a struggling infant to a
mature, prosperous adult. State highway construction, responding to the
flood of new cars bought following World War II, made trucking faster
and cheaper. But the real boon was construction of the interstate
highway system, which permitted truckers to compete seriously with
railroads for long-distance freight. With the highways began a movement
of industry away from rail sites and into suburban and rural areas
serviceable by trucks. The industrialization of the South, which had few
railroads to start with, also benefited trucking as it hurt the rails.
The
highway network, combined with significant increases in standard truck
size (from twenty-seven feet in the late 1940s to forty-five feet thirty
years later), and the inherent advantage of being able to offer
door-to- door delivery, produced a rate of growth in motor carriage far
greater than that of the economy itself. By 1980, interstate trucking
earned $67 billion a year, accounting for over 70 percent of interstate
freight revenues. In 1979, the average family spent $800 a year for
interstate truck transportation, which is a hidden cost in virtually
every product the consumer buys. Of that, about 46 percent-$31 billion
total-went to motor carriers regulated by the ICC.
The basic
regulatory system that shaped the growth of the entire industry has been
described. Many of the policies described were modified or eliminated
in the late 1970s by the ICC; the Motor Carrier Act of 1980 essentially
codified changes made by a commission that became increasingly reform
minded as the prospect of legislative deregulation increased. Other
aspects of the system were preserved; the 1980 act reduced regulatory
controls on the trucking industry, but it did not eliminate them
altogether.
Entry
ICC controls on trucking (like
the earlier state controls) were modeled after classical public-utility
regulation. The traditional rationale for such regulation is that
certain enterprises–like the telephone industry, railroads, and
electric utilities–are “natural monopolies.” The technology of these
industries is (or once was) such that it would be wasteful to society to
have more than one company take on the enormous cost of stringing phone
lines or laying track. Since the average cost per connection goes down
as the network expands, one competitor will inevitably emerge as the
sole provider–or “natural monopolist.” In return for protecting the
naturally monopolistic industry from competition, regulation requires
that it provide service to all who desire it–what’s known as the
common-carrier obligation. Thus the phone company can’t refuse to
connect lines to a new home just because it’s out of the way.
The
motor carrier industry was regulated as a public utility, even though
it did not fit the description of a natural monopoly and that was not
the rationale for the 1935 act. The ICC granted trucking firms
near-exclusive operating rights to carry certain commodities on certain
routes. In principle, these firms performed a common-carrier obligation
in return.
The great majority of common-carrier operating rights
held even in the late 1970s were issued under the “grandfather clause”
of the Motor Carrier Act Given automatically to (18,000) trucking
companies that were in business in 1935, the grandfather rights
authorized them to maintain their existing routes and service. Later,
operating rights became much more difficult to obtain.
New
operating authority required a showing of “public convenience and
necessity,” the watchwords of the 1935 act. An applicant had the burden
of proving that existing firms weren’t already providing a needed
service and that they wouldn’t be financially damaged by the additional
competition. That a new carrier promised to offer an existing service at
a lower cost was by law not relevant to the ICC.
Entry
applications were open to challenge by established carriers, and
requests for significant operating authority were almost always
litigated–a process that could take up to two or more years and
$250,000. As a result, applicants often struck deals with would-be
competitors, narrowing the scope of their request in return for
withdrawal of the legal challenge. Other requests were narrowly drawn to
begin with so as to avoid litigation. Thus while the ICC technically
granted a very high percentage of all applications for operating rights,
the effect on competition was negligible. Most amounted to
insubstantial requests, and from existing carriers at that. (Because
operating rights were so narrowly defined, carriers had to apply
continually for new authority to meet changing freight demands resulting
from, for example, construction of a new factory or warehouse.)
Since
entry was so tightly restricted, trucking firms typically acquired
rights by buying them from an existing carrier. Operating certificates,
like broadcast licenses and taxicab medallions, had a market value. For
many companies, these certificates were their most valuable asset, and
banks routinely accepted them as collateral on loans.
Most
coveted were the “general commodity, regular route” certificates, which
represented common-carrier authority to truck all but legally exempt
goods over designated (“regular”) routes. Those licenses were so
lucrative that, in 1977, the eight largest trucking companies–all of
which held them–earned a rate of return on equity twice that of the
average Fortune 500 company.
General commodity carriers engage in
“less-than-truckload” operations–the heart of the motor carrier
business. An LTL operation involves diverse cargoes of packaged freight
and requires large terminals with loading docks where the cargo can be
assembled for shipment or reassigned to local fleets for final delivery.
LTL service makes transportation of many small shipments economically
feasible–a service no other form of surface transportation can
duplicate. Only 1,000 of the 17,000 trucking companies that were
regulated in 1979 were general commodity carriers, but they accounted
for two-thirds of total regulated trucking revenue. Each of the three
largest general commodity carriers–Roadway Express, Consolidated
Freightways–and Yellow Freight System–earned close to a billion
dollars in 1979.
Most of the remaining firms regulated by the ICC
were specialized, irregular route common carriers. These firms, which
rely heavily on owner-operators to perform the actual transportation,
haul truckload (TL) shipments of a homogeneous cargo using specially
tailored equipment such as refrigerated trucks (“reefers”), armored
cars, or automobile trailers. Specialized carrier rights-less valued
than LTL rights because of competition from railroads for TL
shipments-allowed considerable flexibility with respect to routes but
authorized only a narrow range of specified commodities.
This
system of assigning rights produced some bizarre restrictions. A
specialized carrier, for example, might be allowed to carry exposed film
but not unexposed film, or lead pipe but not plastic pipe. General
freight carriers were often forced to take long, roundabout routes
because their authority represented a “tacking” together of operating
rights acquired through purchase and merger. Many operating rights
contained only one-way authority; thus carriers were legally barred from
carrying a load on their return trip (backhaul), even if cargo was
readily available to be shipped.
Overall, the ICC’s system of
route and commodity restrictions served to divide the market into
thousands of segments, each served by only a few carriers. For shipments
between large cities that were well-served in 1935, when grandfather
rights were issued, there might have been as many as 12 carriers to
choose from. In geographic areas of the country that developed after
1935, the choice was likely between only two or three. Long-distance
shipments often had to be “interlined” between two or more carriers with
adjacent routes.
In addition to general commodity and
specialized common carriers, ICC regulation governed contract
carriage-service to individual shippers on a long-term contract basis,
often using specialized equipment. In recent years, some 3,000 contract
carriers, operating under ICC permits that had negligible market value,
hauled approximately 7 percent of the total regulated tonnage. During
the 1920s and early 1930s, state-regulated common carriers perceived the
contract hauler as a threat because he could attract lucrative freight
by undercutting their published rates-rates that in theory reflected the
added cost of the common-carrier obligation. To prevent what common
carriers argued was cream-skimming, the 1935 act provided for setting a
floor on contract carriage rates. The ICC also limited severely the
number of shippers a contract carrier could serve.
Rates
In
addition to restricting entry, the ICC was authorized to regulate
trucking rates. The need to control excessive rates is apparent, since a
shipper often had little choice as to which carrier could haul his
goods to a given destination. But the major objective of ICC controls
was to prevent rates from being set too low to maintain an acceptable
level of profits and service in the industry. The system that developed
collective ratemaking was well suited to that objective.
Collective
ratemaking in the (regulated) motor carrier industry was performed,
much as it had been historically in the railroad industry, by private
“rate bureaus.” These bureaus–regional organizations run by a full-time
staff and financed by dues from participating carriers–established
rates that were applied uniformly throughout a designated geographic
area. Ten rate bureaus composed of general commodity carriers controlled
the vast majority of trucking shipments within and between regions of
the country.
Rate bureaus operated much like cartels. Carriers
held open meetings at which shippers could testify but then voted in
secret on proposed rates. While this is price-fixing pure and simple, it
was exempted from antitrust action by the Reed-Bulwinkle Act of 1948
passed by Congress over the veto of President Truman.
By law, all
bureau-set rates had to be approved by the ICC. But over the years, the
commission was extremely sympathetic to the industry and protective of
its health. What’s more, the magnitude of the task-several thousand
rates were filed every day–left the ICC little choice but to
rubber-stamp rate-bureau decisions. In 1977, the commission rejected
lesser than 1 percent of the trucking rates filed.
In theory, any
regulated firm was free to undercut the collectively fixed rate, but
few did since the local rate bureau or a rival carrier was sure to
protest. Protests were often filed automatically, regardless of whether
the challengers were directly affected. The most notorious example
involved an exasperated carrier who filed a rate to carry yak fiat from
Omaha to Chicago. Even though yak fat was an imaginary product, thirteen
different carriers challenged the rate!
Rate bureaus
traditionally served other functions besides providing a forum in which
carriers could meet to discuss and set rates. None was more important
than the periodic filing of “general rate increase” proposals, designed
to raise every bureau-published rate by a fixed percentage in response
to higher costs. These proposals, based on average carrier costs, were
routinely approved by the ICC. Unlike most regulated utilities, the
trucking industry was not held to a maximum rate of return, and the
average return on equity for regulated truckers was well above that for
other industries.
Unregulated Trucking
A
substantial sector of the trucking industry was unregulated, technically
speaking. Though not of major size in 1935, this sector accounted for
60 percent of total industry revenue in 1979 and was growing rapidly.
Unregulated trucking companies–primarily private carriers and haulers
of exempt products–did not need ICC approval to operate, but their
services were severely restricted by the ICC nonetheless.
Private
carriers are actually shippers who choose to haul their own goods. In
1935, only a small percentage of industry freight went by private truck;
by 1978, that share of tonnage had grown to 40 percent. Some of the
largest private carriers–Sears Roebuck, for example–have fleets of
more than 1,000 trucks.
The dramatic growth in private trucking
came about despite ICC regulations. In general, private carriers were
barred from soliciting freight on a commercial basis. (The major
rationale was the potential for a private carrier to subsidize his
transportation operations out of his non-transportation operations and
thus gain a competitive advantage.) Since the normal flow of goods for
an individual shipper is in only one direction, private carriers’
backhauls were generally empty.
Empty backhauls were also a
chronic problem for the 100,000 or more owner-operators who made a
living hauling unprocessed food–the other major form of unregulated
trucking. An exempt trucker who carried tomatoes to a cannery could not
haul canned tomatoes–a regulated commodity–back to the growing area.
To avoid “deadheading,” many independent truckers carried nonexempt
goods on the return haul under temporary contract to a (specialized)
regulated carrier–a practice known as trip-leasing. (Also common was
the hauling of “hot” freight.)
Other owner-operators worked under
permanent contract to regulated carriers. Under this system–much as
with trip-leasing–the certified carrier provided operating rights plus
managerial services in return for a 20 to 30 percent commission.
(Critics of regulation termed this practice “share- cropping.”) Many
specialized commodities–such as household goods and steel–were carried
almost exclusively by owner-operators working under long-term contract.
Economic Objections to Regulation
A
common view is that regulated firms naturally abhor regulation and
would prefer their “freedom.” But the regulated firms in the trucking
industry are the very last to want freedom …In this sense, regulation
is topsy-turvy. Rather than protecting consumers from the vices of
“unbridled enterprise,” regulation is protecting regulated enterprises
from the discipline of the marketplace.
Economists criticized the
idea of regulating the trucking industry almost from the beginning.
Their basic theoretical argument can be simply stated: Trucking is an
inherently competitive industry which, when allowed to operate by
free-market rules, does an efficient job of allocating and pricing
trucking services. The industry possesses neither of the characteristics
of a natural monopoly–high capital costs (or other natural barriers to
entry) and large economies of scale. Only in LTL operations, which
require expensive terminals and a large volume of shipments to run
efficiently, might one find significant concentration, but even there,
the economies of scale are exhausted far short of monopoly control. And
the truckload sector–made up of tens of thousands of small firms, many
of them operating just a single rig–is almost a textbook example of a
competitive industry.
Regulation’s defenders often counter that
the trucking industry should be sheltered from competition because, like
a public utility, motor common carriers have an obligation to provide
service. The economist’s first response is that such an argument puts
the cart before the horse. The common-carrier obligation is the
necessary result of a regulated system in which consumers have no
alternative supplier, not the justification for it. Second, there is no
evidence that ICC-regulated common carriers actually honor that
obligation, which is impossible to enforce anyway; trucking firms serve
out-of-the-way places, but only when it’s profitable to do so.
While
trucking was regulated as if it were a natural monopoly, the rationale
for the 1935 act–aside from protection of railroads–was that the
industry was too competitive, with alleged results–chaos, cutthroat
pricing, excess capacity–that were destructive to the trucking
industry, shippers, and ultimately the public. Even if that rationale
was valid during the Depression, it ceased to be long ago.
Destructive competition is a “theoretical novelty” about which economists have argued for years, according to James Miller:
It
is still not clear whether even in theory destructive competition is
feasible (assuming that firms in the industry are rational profit
maximizers). But if it is, the requirements are that the industry has
substantial fixed costs and that demand be either quite unstable or
secularly declining. The interstate trucking industry simply does not
fit these requirements. Although there are some fixed costs, the vast
majority of costs are variable. As a matter of fact, the ICC uses a rule
of thumb that 90 percent of all trucking costs are variable. Also,
though demand fluctuates, with seasonal peaks in various areas of the
country and for different commodities, its overall pattern is fairly
predictable. Finally, as is well known, the demand for trucking has
grown rather steadily over time.
That growth in trucking demand
came partly at the expense of railroads, and one argument for continued
regulation of trucking-echoing the concerns of the 1930s-was the need to
prevent further diversion of freight from rails. This raises
considerations related to the theory of the second- best, which states
that when distortions exist in one part of the economy (e.g., certain
aspects of railroad regulation), it is not necessarily efficient to
correct distortions in other parts (e.g., trucking regulation). However
economists have also shown that second-best considerations do not hold
insofar as the distortions are the source of excessive costs of
operation. It is always desirable to correct imperfections that lead to
smaller output.
In sum, the major arguments for treating the
trucking industry like a public utility–to prevent industry
concentration, assure service to out-of- the-way places, and hinder
destructive competition–have little basis in theory and scant empirical
support. Nor are second-best considerations with respect to railroads
compelling. What theory and evidence point to, rather, is a system that
produces monopoly profits, excessive costs, inefficient price–service
options, and discriminatory rates–in short, a system that benefits the
regulated industry at great cost to the public.
Monopoly Profits
Regulation
provided the two conditions necessary for cartelization: barriers to
entry and a means of price fixing. Rate bureaus could set prices well
above cost without fear of being undercut by new firms. As a result,
regulated carriers received monopoly “rents.”
The clearest
evidence of monopoly profits is the value the market placed on operating
certificates granted free by the ICC. If profits were normal, no one
would pay for the right to enter the industry.
Various estimates
placed the total value of operating certificates prior to deregulation
at several billion dollars. In 1974, the ATA reported that in recent
acquisitions, operating rights had generally sold for amounts equal to
15 to 20 percent of the revenue produced by those rights. Using ATA
figures, the White House Council on Wage and Price Stability estimated
that industry rights were worth $3 billion to $4 billion. In an
independent study of twenty-three attempts to purchase certificates,
Thomas Gale Moore confirmed the ATA’s judgment: Buyers on average paid
about 15 percent of the expected annual revenue for the rights they
purchased. Based on that figure, Moore estimated that large and
medium-sized carriers owned rights worth between $2.1 billion and $3
billion.
Other evidence of monopoly profits comes from the 1950s,
when unusual circumstances produced a virtual controlled experiment. A
series of court decisions forced the ICC to broaden the exemption of
unprocessed agricultural goods to include fresh and frozen poultry and
frozen fruits and vegetables. The U.S. Department of Agriculture
conducted “before” and “after” studies in different markets and
concluded that deregulation led to both lower rates and improved
service. Shipping rates for fresh poultry fell by 12 to 53 percent, for
an average of 33 percent. For frozen poultry the average decline was 36
percent. (Averages for poultry are unweighted.) Rates for frozen fruits
and vegetables declined by 19 percent on average. After Congress
reregulated frozen fruits and vegetables in 1958, shipping rates rose.
Variations
on intrastate trucking controls have also enabled economists to conduct
crude natural experiments. Trucking within the state of New Jersey is
unregulated. Rates there were found to be 10 to 25 percent lower than
for comparable interstate shipments. In Maryland, where intrastate
household-goods moving is unregulated, rates were found to be 27 to 87
percent below those of interstate movers. International comparisons also
found that trucking rates in countries with little or no regulation
were substantially lower than those in regulated countries.
Still
other evidence of monopoly profits comes from a comparison of brokerage
commissions in the regulated and unregulated sectors. Regulated
carriers typically claimed 20 to 30 percent of the revenues earned by
owner-operators working under a leasing arrangement. This commission
paid for services-insurance, marketing, management-and rental of
operating rights. In the exempt sector, agricultural brokers charged 7
to 10 percent for the same services. The difference in commission rates
would seem to represent a monopoly rent on ICC certificates.
Excessive Costs
ICC
controls enabled carriers to set rates above cost, but they also raised
the cost of operation itself-for both regulated and unregulated
truckers. The evidence here is more qualitative, as analysts have been
hard put to quantify the economic effects.
Route and commodity
restrictions are one likely source of inefficiency, leading to
unnecessary circuitry, low load factors, and excessive interlining
(i.e., transfer of cargo between shippers), all of which consume
gasoline and labor. Various studies have reported finding high rates of
empty backhauling, particularly among exempt and private carriers, but
it’s hard to say how much of total industry underutilization was caused
by ICC restrictions.
The ICC’s system of rate regulation was another
source of excessive costs. Particularly in the LTL sector–where general
rate increases were based on average industry costs–the system
protected less efficient firms. That protection was limited, however, in
areas where (LTL) carriers could compete on the basis of service.
The
general rate-increase mechanism also led to higher labor costs. Since
over 60 percent of motor carrier operating expenses go for labor, a rise
in Teamster wages was usually sufficient to trigger an across-the-board
increase in bureau-set rates. Regulated carriers had less incentive to
resist union demands, knowing they could pass the cost along to their
customers automatically. Any single firm had an incentive to reduce its
costs, but the industry as a collective bargainer faced no such
incentive. (While high wages are treated here as an “excessive cost” of
operation, they more accurately represent a monopoly rent to organized
labor.)
Regulation tends to increase wages through another effect
as well. It strengthens union power by preventing nonunion firms from
entering the industry and competing for traffic carried by unionized
firms. Based on an empirical study of these two effects, Moore estimated
that regulation–unionization produced gains to Teamsters employed in
the trucking industry of between $1 billion and $1.3 billion in 1972.
Inefficient Price-Service Options
In
the same way banks offered depositors free checking accounts and other
bonuses to get around federal ceilings on interest rates, many regulated
truckers offered better service–such as more frequent pickup or
rush-hour delivery–in place of cheaper rates. When regulation restricts
rival firms from lowering prices, they will inevitably compete by
offering customers better service. Additional service raises operating
costs. While this is not intrinsically bad, service competition is
inefficient because customers generally don’t value the additional
service at what it costs to provide it. On the plus side, the service is
worth something to customers, and it serves to reduce monopoly rents as
it restores consumer surplus.
While regulated carriers found
limited ways to circumvent ICC controls, shippers were still faced with
inflexible and inefficient rate-service (price-quality) choices. Some
shippers would have preferred less service at a lower rate. Others would
have gladly paid a premium for still better service. Collective
ratemaking precluded this, however, and thus distorted shippers’
decisions about such things as where to locate, when to schedule
production, and how large an inventory to maintain.
Discriminatory Rates
Other
distortions resulted from the rate structure for regulated trucking. To
prevent individual shippers from being arbitrarily advantaged by
preferential treatment or efficiency differences between carriers, the
ICC required regulated firms to charge “equal rates for equal miles” to
shippers moving similar freight. But when costs varied, some shippers
were overcharged and others were subsidized.
For example,
regulated carriers charged the same rates for backhaul (the direction
with the light load) as for prime haul, even though backhaul costs are
lower because of the additional capacity. This affected shippers’
locational decisions and discriminated against certain regions, because
traffic to an area tends to be either predominantly prime haul or
predominantly backhaul. The “equal rates for equal miles” rule also
precluded peak-load pricing. Thus shippers had no incentive to take
advantage of off-season months, when carrier costs are lower.
Another
form of price discrimination resulted from regulated truckers’ policy
of charging more for high-value goods than for low-value goods that cost
the same to transport. The greater the market value of a product
relative to its transportation costs, carriers reasoned the less
concerned shippers would be with freight prices. Thus truckers charged
twice as much to haul nylon as cotton hosiery out of South Carolina. The
shipping rate for champagne was considerably higher than that for
ginger ale.
This system of price discrimination eventually proved
counterproductive as certain shippers resorted to more expensive (to
society) alternatives such as private carriage or air freight. The loss
of “good freight”–freight assigned rates that were especially high
relative to cost- eventually became one of the most serious problems
faced by the regulated trucking industry.
In sum, ICC regulation
produced monopoly profits, excessive costs, and other inefficiencies
resulting from inflexible price-quality choices and rate discrimination.
The price tag to consumers, by many estimates, was billions of dollars
annually.
Who benefited from this system? Most directly, the
owners of ICC certificates did; but only the original owners, oddly
enough. Those who bought certificates earned no more than a competitive
rate of return when the cost of the certificates was taken into account.
As with any asset, the value of future earnings made possible by
ownership gets capitalized into its price.
Labor was the other
major beneficiary of ICC regulation. Teamsters, like certificate owners,
earned economic rents in that cartelization of the industry, combined
with unionization, resulted in wages higher than would have been
necessary to entice them to work. Moore estimated that between 74 and 97
percent of the cost to consumers of ICC regulation ($3.4 billion in
1972 by his calculations) was rent to capital and labor.
Trucking
regulation had other, less direct beneficiaries. Among them were the
3,500 attorneys who comprised the ICC Practitioners’ Association.
Employees of the ATA, member conferences, state trucking associations,
and rate bureaus also benefited. These individuals were evidence for the
argument that a large portion of monopoly rents will often be spent on
trying to protect the monopoly.